22. November 2014 · Categories: Copyright

It seems that the EU wants to make injunctions the default remedy in patent cases. This is quite troubling because of the hold up nature of patents: it means you could extort an disproportionate rent from accidental use of a minor infraction. It will mainly aid patent trolls, since it seems important safeguards are missing:

  • You can pursue an injunction even before you have a ruling on the validity. Given how many crappy patents are issued, this is a huge problem.

  • There is no proportionality with regard to the actual value of the patent. Many infringements happen because the invention is close to obvious and has been independently recreated. This means the invention should be considered nearly useless, and not be available for extortion.

  • There is no recognition that the negotiation overhead for possible hundreds of patents needed for typical computer based techniques would be prohibitive for small companies, and could strongly inhibit innovations.

24. December 2012 · Categories: Copyright

One of the great deceptions in the discussion about copyrights is its length. With a discount rate of just 4%, a 40 year copyright term would capture 80% of full value of the work. But when we look at the actual works, we see that most are popular for at most a year, maybe 5 years. So granting any longer copyright terms would not help much in generating revenues, and if a work is not popular within 40 years, it will almost never become it later, and it certainly will not provide the income that allows the creator to pursue further works.

The main argument used to justify longer terms is as an old age provision for the artist. Since a work would only generate a meager income 40 years later, it will not help the average artist very much. It would be much better to help them save for their old age. Sportsmen are in the same boat; after 35 they need a new carrier or live of their savings. Artists do not need a special deal.

The real benefactors are the lucky few holders to the rights of evergreens. They still generate a nice income, but we must not forget that the holders would already have been amply rewarded in the first 40 years. There is no need to keep rewarding people for their ideas forever.

The other argument used is brand protection. When you create a popular figure you want to keep the right to exploit it, and you do not want any imitators to produce low quality lookalikes. But this is a job we should not burden copyright law with; there are already frameworks in trademark law that can be used, and we need to make sure that we do not kill fan fiction with it as well. If we look at the successful Disney franchises, they live from renewing their characters, not from reprints of 40+ old stories. And they want to keep the control not for the old stories, but to retain profits and control over marketing tie ins.

The last point is about artistic integrity. But provisions about which versions can be called the real thing are completely separate from who should be allowed to produce them, and royalties.

When we talk about copyright, we should not loose sight that it is an artificial monopoly created by the state to encourage the creation of works. It costs money to police it, and it reduces the ability to interact with them. These are expensive enough that limiting the copyright term to 80% of the value of an infinite monopoly sounds like a brilliant deal. This is a 40 year term when assuming a 4% discount rate, an incredibly generous assumption. For example companies demand a discount rate of 8% to 12% when calculating whether to start a product, because of the inherent uncertainty in any projection of the future. Nobody uses the returns 40 years from now when calculating where to invest, the uncertainty is just too great. The terms are so long not because they would encourage more creative works, they are the result of lobbying by the lucky few millionaires and companies owning the few really profitable properties and wanting to extract extra rent from the public. Long copyrights are not for needy poor artists, they are for greedy rich bastards.

27. August 2012 · Categories: Apple, Copyright

With the jury handing Apple a huge win against Samsung (Florian Müller has a good overview), I feel conflicted in my reaction. On the one hand I welcome it as Samsung has been quite willful in copying the iPhone almost verbatim, and they have definitely crossed the line of decency here, on the other hand the asserted patents are uncomfortably close to core touch screen functionality: the over scroll bounce patent, tap to zoom, pinch to zoom. If you remember that Apple also has patents about gesture detection heuristic and inertial scrolling on the books, then this amounts to a monopoly for still another 15 years on very essential user interface paradigms for touch screens.

These are important breakthroughs, but the problem is the balkanization of user interfaces this would bring. While the vendors would love the extra lock in, it is not good for society to have every touch screen device use its own touch vocabulary. The conventions were pretty much in the air when the iPhone debuted (see this brilliant TED talk), and their core (that is everything using at most two fingers, plus the four finger swipe) should be available to everyone. Otherwise we get what the situation with cars was 100 years ago. Can you imagine not finding the accelerator or the brake pedal? That used to be quite normal, and this is not a situation I want to see for touch screen interfaces. They will be just too pervasive that it can be acceptable to have to relearn them between devices.

After all, patents are not a god given right, but a creation of men to encourage extra research and development. They were created because for society the benefit of extra innovation is higher than the licenses one would have to pay to the inventors, and the slower spread of the invention because of extra costs. But I honestly do not think that this should entitle Apple to a payment in the hundreds of billion dollars, as they believe is their due. They demand 30$ per unit, we can expect 7.5 replacements in the next 15 years per consumer, and have half a billion users likely growing to 2 billion people.

Apple has already been richly rewarded, while being quite stingy with the actual inventors behind these patents, none of them even remotely getting anything close to what Tim Cook is making. So the appropriate way to deal with it would be to give Apple say 10 million dollar per patent in compensation, and then put these into the public domain. After all these inventions would likely have been discovered independently by now.

 

03. April 2012 · Categories: Copyright

There are two points of criticism with Readabilty:

  • First that they link to their own reformatted copies of content. This is bad, and in violation of copyright law. But they seem to come around and change this.
  • Secondly that they promise to pay 70% to the content creators. They do not keep this promise, because they keep the money if not claimed by publications within a year. They should then distribute this old money among those publications that have actually registered.

But these can easily be solved. And we will see from their reaction how serious they are and if these shady sounding practices were a mistake.

The true problem however lies with the publishers. It is their decision to provide layouts that are not well suited to reading, in the name of serving the advertising gods. But honestly advertising needs to remain rare enough that it will not become clutter and so profoundly ignored, and it really was this advertising overload that gave rise to Readabilty, Instapaper and other reading tools. Without dynamic pages caused by advertising we could even actually use our browser to do proper offline reading.

20. February 2009 · Categories: Copyright

Again, again, we are here, discussing copyright extensions. Simple question: Why should society create an artificial monopoly on intellectual property? To reward people doing this work. How high does this reward need to be? High enough for people to be willing to do this work, to be motivated to do the work.

Let us see how much people get from a limited copyright. We compare the revenue stream from the copyright to the money they would get if they invested it at a certain rate. Now an invention will normally be most popular when conceived, and become less valuable over time. To model this, we simply add the rate of decline in popularity to our investment rate. So we treat 5% investment rate and 5% annual decline in revenues as a 10% alternative investment rate. This will give us the following table to see how much of the overall revenues you get from an invention or a copyrighted piece:

Interest Rate
1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% 10%
Duration
in years
10 9.5% 18.0% 25.6% 32.4% 38.6% 44.2% 49.2% 53.7% 57.8% 61.4%
20 18.0% 32.7% 44.6% 54.4% 62.3% 68.8% 74.2% 78.5% 82.2% 85.1%
30 25.8% 44.8% 58.8% 69.2% 76.9% 82.6% 86.9% 90.1% 92.5% 94.3%
40 32.8% 54.7% 69.3% 79.2% 85.8% 90.3% 93.3% 95.4% 96.8% 97.8%
50 39.2% 62.8% 77.2% 85.9% 91.3% 94.6% 96.6% 97.9% 98.7% 99.1%
60 45.0% 69.5% 83.0% 90.5% 94.6% 97.0% 98.3% 99.0% 99.4% 99.7%

Table: Current value of a limited revenue stream compared to CV of the perpetual stream

It is quite interesting to see how quickly compound interest is reducing the value of an invention. I believe that 75% of the value to the inventor / creator and 25% to the public is more than a fair split to encourage innovation, and with a 5% depreciation rate which I believe to be pretty generous (many companies do not start projects that promise at least a 10% return), that would mean that 30 years are the correct duration of a copyright.